Politics

/

ArcaMax

Bill Dudley: Ted Cruz has a weird idea about the Federal Reserve

Bill Dudley, Bloomberg Opinion on

Published in Op Eds

In their efforts to offset tax cuts and exert more control over the Federal Reserve, some U.S. legislators have lately focused attention on an otherwise obscure element of monetary policy: The Fed, they argue, should stop paying interest on the cash reserves that banks hold at the central bank.

It's a bad idea, in more ways than one.

The authority to pay interest on reserves, a power granted to the Fed by Congress in 2008, has enhanced the Fed’s ability to support the economy. It puts a floor on short-term interest rates, because banks have little incentive to charge less than what they can earn risk-free at the central bank. It encourages banks to keep plenty of reserves, helping ensure that they have enough cash to meet unexpected demands and to satisfy the liquidity requirements that were considerably strengthened following the Great Financial Crisis. It allows the central bank to provide emergency liquidity to the financial system without undermining its monetary policy.

Yet suddenly, legislators want to eliminate the practice. Some, notably Senator Ted Cruz, posit that doing so would save the U.S. government more than $1 trillion over the next decade. Others think it’s necessary to shrink the Fed’s $6.7 trillion balance sheet, which they say unduly exposes taxpayers to losses and gives the central bank too large of a footprint in financial markets. These ideas are misguided.

Let’s start with the supposed savings. For the Fed, reserves are created when it increases its holdings of interest-earning assets such as Treasury securities. If it stopped paying interest, banks would reduce their reserves to the bare minimum needed to execute payments into and out of their accounts at the Fed.

This, in turn, would require the Fed to sell off assets to restore the balance between the demand and supply of reserves. Otherwise, short-term interest rates would plummet to zero. The reduction in the Fed’s balance sheet, in turn, would reduce its interest income. With both sides of its balance sheet shrinking by the same amount, its profits and its remittances to the U.S. Treasury wouldn’t materially change.

True, the size and composition of the Fed’s balance sheet entails some risks: Its pandemic-era asset purchases, for example, have resulted in more than $200 billion in losses to taxpayers. But this isn’t the fault of interest on reserves. It happened because the central bank invested the reserves in longer-dated assets, then had to push up short-term rates sharply to combat inflation. As a result, the interest payments on reserves overwhelmed the income earned on the assets, precipitating losses. One can argue that the Fed’s asset purchase program and interest-rate policy were flawed, but those are separate issues.

Should the Fed have a smaller footprint? I don’t see why. This would effectively entail a return to the pre-2008 regime, in which banks had to closely manage their reserves, borrowing from one another whenever they found themselves short of cash. Central bank reserves are the ultimate high-quality liquid asset. Why shouldn’t the Fed provide as much as needed to enable banks to meet their obligations?

Beyond that, paying interest on reserves — and hence maintaining a larger balance sheet — makes the Fed’s job easier in numerous ways. As long as reserves are ample — that is, above the level that banks need for liquidity and payments — the central bank need only change the interest rate on those reserves to affect short-term rates more broadly. It needn’t tinker with the quantity of reserves in the banking system.

 

By contrast, under the previous scarce-reserves regime, the Fed had to ensure that supply met demand precisely. This was difficult because events beyond its control — such as fluctuations in the Treasury’s cash balance at the Fed or the demand for currency — affected the amount of reserves. To keep the federal funds rate within its target range, the Fed had to impose a complicated set of reserve requirements for banks and conduct frequent open-market operations.

The current regime also bolsters the Fed’s ability to act as the lender of last resort and to intervene effectively during financial crises. Under the pre-2008 regime, it had to limit the size of its special liquidity facilities in order to ensure that usage would not undermine its control of interest rates. Now, it can provide an open-ended backstop, which is far more credible and hence effective in restoring market function and financial stability.

In sum, prohibiting the Fed from paying interest on reserves wouldn’t save money, wouldn’t protect taxpayers and would undermine the central bank’s ability to stabilize financial markets and the economy. Legislators should drop this very bad idea.

_____

This column reflects the personal views of the author and does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial board or Bloomberg LP and its owners.

Bill Dudley is a Bloomberg Opinion columnist. A former president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, he is a nonexecutive director at Swiss Bank UBS and a member of Coinbase Global's advisory council.

_____


©2025 Bloomberg L.P. Visit bloomberg.com/opinion. Distributed by Tribune Content Agency, LLC.

 

Comments

blog comments powered by Disqus

 

Related Channels

ACLU

ACLU

By The ACLU
Amy Goodman

Amy Goodman

By Amy Goodman
Armstrong Williams

Armstrong Williams

By Armstrong Williams
Austin Bay

Austin Bay

By Austin Bay
Ben Shapiro

Ben Shapiro

By Ben Shapiro
Betsy McCaughey

Betsy McCaughey

By Betsy McCaughey
Bill Press

Bill Press

By Bill Press
Bonnie Jean Feldkamp

Bonnie Jean Feldkamp

By Bonnie Jean Feldkamp
Cal Thomas

Cal Thomas

By Cal Thomas
Christine Flowers

Christine Flowers

By Christine Flowers
Clarence Page

Clarence Page

By Clarence Page
Danny Tyree

Danny Tyree

By Danny Tyree
David Harsanyi

David Harsanyi

By David Harsanyi
Debra Saunders

Debra Saunders

By Debra Saunders
Dennis Prager

Dennis Prager

By Dennis Prager
Dick Polman

Dick Polman

By Dick Polman
Erick Erickson

Erick Erickson

By Erick Erickson
Froma Harrop

Froma Harrop

By Froma Harrop
Jacob Sullum

Jacob Sullum

By Jacob Sullum
Jamie Stiehm

Jamie Stiehm

By Jamie Stiehm
Jeff Robbins

Jeff Robbins

By Jeff Robbins
Jessica Johnson

Jessica Johnson

By Jessica Johnson
Jim Hightower

Jim Hightower

By Jim Hightower
Joe Conason

Joe Conason

By Joe Conason
Joe Guzzardi

Joe Guzzardi

By Joe Guzzardi
John Micek

John Micek

By John Micek
John Stossel

John Stossel

By John Stossel
Josh Hammer

Josh Hammer

By Josh Hammer
Judge Andrew Napolitano

Judge Andrew Napolitano

By Judge Andrew P. Napolitano
Laura Hollis

Laura Hollis

By Laura Hollis
Marc Munroe Dion

Marc Munroe Dion

By Marc Munroe Dion
Michael Barone

Michael Barone

By Michael Barone
Mona Charen

Mona Charen

By Mona Charen
Rachel Marsden

Rachel Marsden

By Rachel Marsden
Rich Lowry

Rich Lowry

By Rich Lowry
Robert B. Reich

Robert B. Reich

By Robert B. Reich
Ruben Navarrett Jr

Ruben Navarrett Jr

By Ruben Navarrett Jr.
Ruth Marcus

Ruth Marcus

By Ruth Marcus
S.E. Cupp

S.E. Cupp

By S.E. Cupp
Salena Zito

Salena Zito

By Salena Zito
Star Parker

Star Parker

By Star Parker
Stephen Moore

Stephen Moore

By Stephen Moore
Susan Estrich

Susan Estrich

By Susan Estrich
Ted Rall

Ted Rall

By Ted Rall
Terence P. Jeffrey

Terence P. Jeffrey

By Terence P. Jeffrey
Tim Graham

Tim Graham

By Tim Graham
Tom Purcell

Tom Purcell

By Tom Purcell
Veronique de Rugy

Veronique de Rugy

By Veronique de Rugy
Victor Joecks

Victor Joecks

By Victor Joecks
Wayne Allyn Root

Wayne Allyn Root

By Wayne Allyn Root

Comics

John Cole Jack Ohman A.F. Branco David Horsey Gary McCoy Dana Summers